Welcome to Bookmarker!

This is a personal project by @dellsystem. I built this to help me retain information from the books I'm reading.

Source code on GitHub (MIT license).

47

State Power and the Power of Money

1
terms
8
notes

Mann, G. (2013). State Power and the Power of Money. In Mann, G. Disassembly Required: A Field Guide to Actually Existing Capitalism. AK Press, pp. 47-76

49

When we think of state power over territory, we think precisely of what defines the state as the state. In sociologist Max Weber's classic definition, the state is that set of institutions which enjoys "the monopoly of the legitimate use of physical force within a given territory." This power is coercive: the state, by virtue of its control over the police, law, military, etc., has the power to coerce you, if you are inside its territory, to do or not do certain things, and to punish you if you don't follow the rules, which the state itself determines. Virtually all capitalist states limit these powers via laws, constitutions and "bills of rights," for example requiring the police to have a warrant to enter and search your home. But the state (at least in theory) remains the sole possessor of this territorially defined coercive power.

from From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology (essay "Politics as Vocation")

—p.49 by Geoff Mann 6 years, 8 months ago

When we think of state power over territory, we think precisely of what defines the state as the state. In sociologist Max Weber's classic definition, the state is that set of institutions which enjoys "the monopoly of the legitimate use of physical force within a given territory." This power is coercive: the state, by virtue of its control over the police, law, military, etc., has the power to coerce you, if you are inside its territory, to do or not do certain things, and to punish you if you don't follow the rules, which the state itself determines. Virtually all capitalist states limit these powers via laws, constitutions and "bills of rights," for example requiring the police to have a warrant to enter and search your home. But the state (at least in theory) remains the sole possessor of this territorially defined coercive power.

from From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology (essay "Politics as Vocation")

—p.49 by Geoff Mann 6 years, 8 months ago
50

This is not to say that the coercive part goes away. You might think, quite reasonably, that since coercion is always hovering in the background, the consent part is a bit of a joke: if you don't consent, you get coerced, meaning the consent is not all that consensual. At the level of the isolated individual, this is true. But if you think about it at a collective level, the consent part is much more evident. If every single person refused to consent, the state's coercive power would almost certainly be insufficient. The stability of the liberal democratic state as an institutional complex depends on the often tacit, sometimes explicit endorsement of its citizenry. Modern state power is constituted by a complicated, shifting, and contingent combination of coercion on the part of the state and consent on the part of the population.

[...] it is not only the state that can coerce. Private economic power rarely lacks some coercive aspect. [...] Banks can push through laws in their interest because the can use their market power to disrupt the whole economy--to coerce the government to meet their demands. [...]

The combination of coercion and consent (operated by both capital and the state) produces a relation known as "hegemony," a term first elaborated in this sense by a justly famous pre-World War II Italian communist named Antonio Gramsci. [...]

Gramsci worked out his idea of hegemony while he was reading the work of Lenin [...] capital's hegemony, its power to shape the "common sense" we tacitly share about the state, the ruling classes, and their power: that those relations are natural, that they serve a necessary function, that they are the only way to keep the peace. Those in power construct an effective hegemony when the existing order appears to be not only in their interests, but in everyone's interest. It is the practices that render a given social formation ideologically "normal".

oh man this is so good

—p.50 by Geoff Mann 6 years, 8 months ago

This is not to say that the coercive part goes away. You might think, quite reasonably, that since coercion is always hovering in the background, the consent part is a bit of a joke: if you don't consent, you get coerced, meaning the consent is not all that consensual. At the level of the isolated individual, this is true. But if you think about it at a collective level, the consent part is much more evident. If every single person refused to consent, the state's coercive power would almost certainly be insufficient. The stability of the liberal democratic state as an institutional complex depends on the often tacit, sometimes explicit endorsement of its citizenry. Modern state power is constituted by a complicated, shifting, and contingent combination of coercion on the part of the state and consent on the part of the population.

[...] it is not only the state that can coerce. Private economic power rarely lacks some coercive aspect. [...] Banks can push through laws in their interest because the can use their market power to disrupt the whole economy--to coerce the government to meet their demands. [...]

The combination of coercion and consent (operated by both capital and the state) produces a relation known as "hegemony," a term first elaborated in this sense by a justly famous pre-World War II Italian communist named Antonio Gramsci. [...]

Gramsci worked out his idea of hegemony while he was reading the work of Lenin [...] capital's hegemony, its power to shape the "common sense" we tacitly share about the state, the ruling classes, and their power: that those relations are natural, that they serve a necessary function, that they are the only way to keep the peace. Those in power construct an effective hegemony when the existing order appears to be not only in their interests, but in everyone's interest. It is the practices that render a given social formation ideologically "normal".

oh man this is so good

—p.50 by Geoff Mann 6 years, 8 months ago
56

Ingham [...] says there are three main ways the state interacts with "the economy," and, although they are not so easily separated, the distinctions are useful. They are:

  1. State provision/production of social peace;
  2. State maintenance of capitalist social relations (often via "liberal democracy"); and
  3. Direct and indirect state participation in the economy.

on Geoffrey Ingham's book Capitalism

also, Ingham says that the state and the capitalist class are thought of as separate, autonomous spheres precisely because they depended on each other and thus let the other operate independently

—p.56 by Geoff Mann 6 years, 8 months ago

Ingham [...] says there are three main ways the state interacts with "the economy," and, although they are not so easily separated, the distinctions are useful. They are:

  1. State provision/production of social peace;
  2. State maintenance of capitalist social relations (often via "liberal democracy"); and
  3. Direct and indirect state participation in the economy.

on Geoffrey Ingham's book Capitalism

also, Ingham says that the state and the capitalist class are thought of as separate, autonomous spheres precisely because they depended on each other and thus let the other operate independently

—p.56 by Geoff Mann 6 years, 8 months ago
57

Successful hegemonic projects necessitate both coercive capacity on the part of the governors and consent on the part of the governed. In other words, the state and the social relations it protects must be granted, at least by a significant part of the population, sufficient legitimacy. Capitalism requires legitimacy. What is not so clear, however, is the means through which it acquires legitimacy: are we fooled into acquiescing to capitalism by cultural institutions like the church, or by transactions that cheat us in ways we don't understand? Are we "bought off" by the welfare state, basic amenities, and the possibility of upward mobility? Is capitalism the "best possible" or "least bad" system, thus meriting our reasoned endorsement? Furthermore, to what extent does the state participate in the legitimation process? If we are dupes, is it the state that dupes us? Capitalists? Both? If we are bought off, surely the state is important, but in whose interest is it acting? Is it extracting from capitalists in the interests of workers? Or is it appeasing workers in the interests of capitalists? There is, of course, no one universal answer to these questions.

this paragraph is so good

—p.57 by Geoff Mann 6 years, 8 months ago

Successful hegemonic projects necessitate both coercive capacity on the part of the governors and consent on the part of the governed. In other words, the state and the social relations it protects must be granted, at least by a significant part of the population, sufficient legitimacy. Capitalism requires legitimacy. What is not so clear, however, is the means through which it acquires legitimacy: are we fooled into acquiescing to capitalism by cultural institutions like the church, or by transactions that cheat us in ways we don't understand? Are we "bought off" by the welfare state, basic amenities, and the possibility of upward mobility? Is capitalism the "best possible" or "least bad" system, thus meriting our reasoned endorsement? Furthermore, to what extent does the state participate in the legitimation process? If we are dupes, is it the state that dupes us? Capitalists? Both? If we are bought off, surely the state is important, but in whose interest is it acting? Is it extracting from capitalists in the interests of workers? Or is it appeasing workers in the interests of capitalists? There is, of course, no one universal answer to these questions.

this paragraph is so good

—p.57 by Geoff Mann 6 years, 8 months ago
58

[...] Consider the following: even if it were true that capitalism and democracy have always gone together (and it is definitively not true), this would in no way justify the claim that they will go together until the end of time. Transhistorical claims originating in particular historical modes of production have never proven true [...]

—p.58 by Geoff Mann 6 years, 8 months ago

[...] Consider the following: even if it were true that capitalism and democracy have always gone together (and it is definitively not true), this would in no way justify the claim that they will go together until the end of time. Transhistorical claims originating in particular historical modes of production have never proven true [...]

—p.58 by Geoff Mann 6 years, 8 months ago
62

[...] It is not a mere tool of any particular class or interest, but is linked in different ways to them all, while enjoying some independence at the same time. It is the "factor of cohesion": its relative autonomy from any one class or class fraction is what makes hegemony in capitalism possible.

Citing Nicos Poulantzas, Political Power and Social Classes and The Poulantzas Reader: Marxism, Law, and the State)

—p.62 by Geoff Mann 6 years, 8 months ago

[...] It is not a mere tool of any particular class or interest, but is linked in different ways to them all, while enjoying some independence at the same time. It is the "factor of cohesion": its relative autonomy from any one class or class fraction is what makes hegemony in capitalism possible.

Citing Nicos Poulantzas, Political Power and Social Classes and The Poulantzas Reader: Marxism, Law, and the State)

—p.62 by Geoff Mann 6 years, 8 months ago
63

[...] relative autonomy allows the state to protect capitalism when capitalists themselves threaten to tear it apart. The state is the ideal institution to protect capitalism from the capitalists, who, when they each act on their own, tend to cause more than minor bumps in the market-mediated road. The state can legitimately coordinate and regulate their actions, and keep information on their actions in ways that the capitalists might hate, but that nonetheless are often the only reason the system works at all.

—p.63 by Geoff Mann 6 years, 8 months ago

[...] relative autonomy allows the state to protect capitalism when capitalists themselves threaten to tear it apart. The state is the ideal institution to protect capitalism from the capitalists, who, when they each act on their own, tend to cause more than minor bumps in the market-mediated road. The state can legitimately coordinate and regulate their actions, and keep information on their actions in ways that the capitalists might hate, but that nonetheless are often the only reason the system works at all.

—p.63 by Geoff Mann 6 years, 8 months ago
66

[...] In standard introductory economics textbooks, money is commonly said to perform four functions: (1) It is a medium of exchange that facilitates the exchange of qualitatively different commodities. (2) It is a means of payment or transaction settlement, the thing with which you settle a debt, and usually legally defined as such. (3) It is a store of value; you can hold it as an asset in the form of abstract or potential purchasing power. (4) It is a unit of account; i.e., the standard unit by which all "economic" values are calculated and compared.

[...] classical and neoclassical economic analysis suggests that all of these functions from an original and primary function, (1) medium of exchange. [...] However, when examined in a more historically sensitive--and analytically adequate--manner, it is clear that as capitalism evolved, money became central primarily because of its key function as a standardized unit of account, which at least in capitalism is the most important role money plays. [...] as a unit of account it represents an abstract claim on or in circulation as a whole. Money measures and stores abstract purchasing power, and transports it through space and time. [...]

his explanation of money is very good here (there are a few more paragraphs on debt creation and the like)

—p.66 by Geoff Mann 6 years, 8 months ago

[...] In standard introductory economics textbooks, money is commonly said to perform four functions: (1) It is a medium of exchange that facilitates the exchange of qualitatively different commodities. (2) It is a means of payment or transaction settlement, the thing with which you settle a debt, and usually legally defined as such. (3) It is a store of value; you can hold it as an asset in the form of abstract or potential purchasing power. (4) It is a unit of account; i.e., the standard unit by which all "economic" values are calculated and compared.

[...] classical and neoclassical economic analysis suggests that all of these functions from an original and primary function, (1) medium of exchange. [...] However, when examined in a more historically sensitive--and analytically adequate--manner, it is clear that as capitalism evolved, money became central primarily because of its key function as a standardized unit of account, which at least in capitalism is the most important role money plays. [...] as a unit of account it represents an abstract claim on or in circulation as a whole. Money measures and stores abstract purchasing power, and transports it through space and time. [...]

his explanation of money is very good here (there are a few more paragraphs on debt creation and the like)

—p.66 by Geoff Mann 6 years, 8 months ago

(noun) a theory in economics that stable economic growth can be assured only by control of the rate of increase of the money supply to match the capacity for growth of real productivity

73

"Monetarism" is the name given to the influential but failed attempt on the part of the neoclassically inspired monetary authorities, during the late 1970s and early 1980s, to control money markets--and therefore the value of money--from the supply side.

—p.73 by Geoff Mann
notable
6 years, 8 months ago

"Monetarism" is the name given to the influential but failed attempt on the part of the neoclassically inspired monetary authorities, during the late 1970s and early 1980s, to control money markets--and therefore the value of money--from the supply side.

—p.73 by Geoff Mann
notable
6 years, 8 months ago